COMMENTARY
Liberal Capital Flows Impacts, Issues and Questions | this in the name of free trade, leading to the notorious Opium Wars. Such examples apart, I accept that, in general, free trade in goods and services |
is beneficial to the buyer and the seller. | |
But is this equally true in respect of | |
A V Rajwade | cross-border movement of capital? Or is |
How far are the arguments favouring the free movement of capital tenable from both empirical evidence and fi rst principles?
A V Rajwade (avrajwade@gmail.com) has been a long-standing commentator on the external sector and fi nancial services.
I
For example, the IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions, September 2011, contends that
The economic benefits of cross-border capital flows are considered to be similar to those emanating from free trade. Capital flows can supplement domestic resources with foreign capital to smooth consumption, boost investment, diversify risk, and deepen financial markets in emerging and developing countries (see Dell’Ariccia and others, 2008). The benefits of capital mobility are reduced when recipient countries attempt to control inflows through the use of measures that lead to suboptimal resource allocation and introduce distortion.
How far are the arguments favouring the free movement of capital tenable from both empirical evidence and fi rst principles? Or are they as self-serving as a few earlier instances of British imperialists using the free trade argument for selfish interests? Let me quote two specifi c instances:
In 1845, when the potato blight hit Ireland, the land was apparently producing enough food for the population there – but the British Empire insisted on continuing to seize and ship it to England. As one contemporary observer wrote, ‘Insane mothers began to eat their young children who died of famine before them; and still fleets of ships were sailing with every tide, carrying Irish cattle and corn to England’, in the interests of free trade (Review by Johann Hari, Three Famines: Starvation and Politics by Thomas Keneally, New York Times Book Review, 16 September 2011). At one time, China was forced by the British Empire to import drugs from India, justifying
may 26, 2012
it, as Jagdish Bhagwati once described, a conspiracy by Wall Street supported by the US Treasury, and propagated by the IMF? More recently, Khairy Tourk of the Stewart School of Business, Chicago, in a letter to the Financial Times (10 March), wrote about the crisis in east Asia that
The 1997 crisis, on the other hand, was a result of an International Monetary Fund policy that reflected Wall Street interests. The US Treasury, in the 1980s, prodded the IMF to push for the immediate liberalisation of the capital account in emerging economies. Such advice ran against the grain of the literature on the sequencing of economic reform.
After the 1997-98 crisis in east Asia the IMF advocacy has been somewhat muted. But the bias keeps coming up.
Let me turn to some of the arguments advanced in the February 2010 IMF Research Department paper “Capital Flows: The Role of Controls”. The paper starts with asserting that “These fl ows, and capital mobility more generally, allow countries with limited savings to attract financing for productive investment projects, foster the diversifi cation of investment risk, promote intertemporal trade, and contribute to the development of financial markets”. True, capital infl ows can finance the savings: investment gap, i e, the deficit on current account. The second gain is “diversification of investment risk”; but surely this is a gain for the investor, and not to the recipient of infl ows?
Financial Markets
What about the development of fi nancial markets? The east Asian crisis was often attributed by analysts to the fact that the relatively less developed fi nancial markets could not absorb the flows for the benefi t of their economies. This argument is, to say the least, very weak. No fi nancial market, howsoever developed, can absorb ever larger capital infl ows without creating financial instability. As Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff argue in their book This Time Is Different, “The US
vol xlviI no 21
EPW
COMMENTARY
conceit that its financial and regulatory system could withstand massive capital inflows on a sustained basis...arguably laid the foundations for the global financial crisis of the 2000s.” The point was conceded by Ben Bernanke, chairman of the US Federal Reserve himself (Financial Times, 20 October 2009) saying that the recent US-centred fi nancial crisis had many similarities with past emerging market crises – fuelled by giant capital inflows that overwhelmed both market discipline and regulatory safeguards. And yet, Bernanke in his February 2011 speech “Global Imbalances: Links to Economic and Financial Stability” argued that, in the Asian crisis, “capital flows posed a problem because of weaknesses in the financial systems and regulatory oversight in countries receiving foreign capital”.
But to come back to the IMF’s February 2010 paper, “inter-temporal trade” means “importing goods today (running a current account deficit) and, in return, exporting goods in the future (running a current account surplus then)” – (“Do Current Account Deficits Matter?”, Atish Ghosh and Uma Ramakrishnan, Finance and Development, December 2006). This once again means that capital infl ows fi nance deficits on the current account. It is good to see even the IMF conceding, if only by implication, that no country can keep on incurring deficits on the current account year after year (unless, of course, your currency is the world’s principal reserve currency) But the problem is that the inflows in the first period may well appreciate the currency so that the surplus in the following year keeps receding. As the 2010 paper itself concedes, while “currency appreciation is likely to be temporary,...damage to the tradable sector (through hysteresis) [lagged effects in English] may be more permanent”.
Given this, one does not know what to make of the following argument in the paper: “if the increase in flows is expected to be more persistent, by contrast, the economy should adjust to the (permanently) higher real exchange rate”.
The IMF’s Global Financial Stability Report, April 2010, articulates the same point slightly differently saying that “more permanent increases in infl ows tend to stem from more fundamental factors, and will require more fundamental economic adjustment”. So the suggestion seems to be that some kinds of capital controls are tolerable if infl ows are transitory, but not if they are of a more permanent nature.
The first objection to this line of thinking is that one cannot foresee whether inflows are transitory or permanent. Even the 2010 paper concedes that
policymakers are again reconsidering the view that… that all fi nancial flows are the result of rational investing/borrowing/lending decisions. Concerns that foreign investors may be subject to herd behaviour, and suffer from excessive optimism, have grown stronger; and even when flows are fundamentally sound, it is recognised that they may contribute to collateral damage, including bubbles and asset booms and busts.
The fact is that too much of investment activity in the domestic or crossborder markets is driven not by a rational analysis of the risks and rewards, but by trying to anticipate “what average opinion expects the average opinion to be” as Keynes said – in other words, the herd instinct. It would be naive to have too much faith in the efficiency of the markets, in the rational expectations of the investors!
Fundamental Adjustments?
But this apart what exactly are the “more fundamental” economic adjustments “to the (permanently) higher real exchange rate” the wise men are referring to? One could be productivity growth in the tradables sector to make the economy competitive at the higher exchange rate. But this surely is a slow, gradual process: the exchange rate can appreciate much faster and do permanent damage to the tradables sector as the paper acknowledges, well before productivity catches up with the exchange rate. The second is defl ation of the domestic economy, through tight monetary and fiscal policy, lower consumption and price levels to make d omestic costs in the tradable sector competitive at the higher exchange rate. A fall in domestic prices would require a cut in wages. The British actually tried this in the 1920s while restoring the pound’s gold parity to pre-fi rst world war levels, succumbing to the arguments of the City that this was needed to maintain London’s position as the global financial capital. It led to a general strike by the unions, and a deep depression inflicting huge misery on the people, before the foolish policy was abandoned. (Currently, Greece is undergoing exactly this treatment.)
The fact is that in a fl oating exchange rate regime, inflows in excess of the current account deficit merely go to appreciate the currency, and asset prices – e quities, real estate, etc – adding little to the productive capacity or growth of the recipient economy. In fact, to quote from an earlier IMF research paper “Financial Globalisation: A Reappraisal” by M Ayhan Kose, Eswar Prasad, Kenneth Rogoff, and Shang-Jin Wei (August 2006), “The majority of empirical studies are unable to find robust evidence in support of the growth benefits of capital account liberalisation”. Jagdish Bhagwati, in his In Defence of Globalisation, is highly sceptical of financial globalisation, as distinct from free trade in goods and services, arguing that, “the claims of enormous benefits from free capital mobility are not persuasive”.
The IMF’s 2006 paper also argued that “There is little formal empirical evidence to support the oft-cited claims that financial globalisation in and of itself is responsible for the spate of fi nancial c rises that the world has seen over the last three decades”. To my mind, the key words are “in and of itself”. While there is little to quarrel with the point made, with that proviso, the fact remains that a liberal capital account can amplify and prolong a crisis. One experience from the east Asian crises of 1997-98 is worth noting: Malaysia imposed capital controls and faced far lower costs and hardships than Thailand, Indonesia and South Korea which were countries which took the IMF medicine. Ben Bernanke, in his speech cited above cautioned that, “we have seen a number of episodes in which international capital fl ows have brought with them challenges for macroeconomic adjustment, financial stability, or both... The Asian crisis imposed heavy costs in terms of financial and macroeconomic instability in the affected countries….”
Economic & Political Weekly
EPW
COMMENTARY
Excessive capital inflows can trap the recipient country into a vicious circle. From Mexico in 1994-95 to east Asia in 1997-98, Russia and Brazil (1998), Argentina (2001) and more recently Iceland and Latvia: in each case, the crisis was the result of excessive capital inflows, appreciating domestic currencies leading to an uncompetitive tradables sector, and increasing deficits on the current account. One day “the music stops playing”, resulting in a balance of payments crisis and misery for the people, particularly the relatively worse off. The IMF’s own Independent Evaluation Office concluded that “the crisis (in east Asia) was triggered by massive reversal of capital fl ows, short-term fl ows played a prominent role, and contagion was an important factor...” (“The IMF and Recent Capital Crises”, 2003).
IMF’s Questionable Proposition
Capital Controls and Prudential Policies in Managing Large Inflows” by Karl Habermeier, Annamaria Kokenyne, and Chikako Baba persists with the biases on the subject of capital flows and controls. It contends,
A broader review of the experiences of 13 emerging market economies in the 2000s also does not provide unambiguous support for the effectiveness of capital controls and prudential measures. However, prudential measures appear to have had more success in stemming credit growth and addressing financial stability concerns than capital controls, but they only rarely reduced appreciation pressures and aggregate fl ows.
Clearly, the ideology needs “unambiguous support for the effectiveness of capital controls” but none for propagating the virtues of uncontrolled capital
Table: Incidence of Financial Crises
Period | Number of Crises |
---|---|
1 | 2 |
1875-1913 | 58 |
1919-39 | 51 |
1945-71 | 17 |
1973-2007 | 399 |
century after the second world war, and
(ii) that this was the period with the least number of crises as compared to the prewar era or the last three decades (see the table).
Even Bernanke conceded that “Those countries that have allowed their exchange rates to be determined primarily by market forces have seen their competitiveness erode relative to countries that have intervened more aggressively in foreign exchange markets” (ibid). If fi nancial stability, which the money men keep emphasising, is the objective, it is best to forgo, out of the impossible trinity, liberal capital fl ows but not managed exchange rates or an independent monetary policy. Indeed, volatile exchange rates are an impediment to greater globalisation of the real economy! On the subject of capital flows and exchange rates, we perhaps need to learn much more from China than from the IMF.
Even in terms of the types of capital inflows to be encouraged, our policy stance seems to be perverse when the objective is promoting growth, employment and financial stability. Surely the hierarchy should be FDI, long-term debt, other equity flows, and lastly the most volatile short-term credit. In terms of our regulatory prescriptions, however, we are most restrictive on the fi rst, and least on the last!
The IMF’s 2010 paper makes another questionable proposition while discussing the sterilisation of an increase in money supply resulting from central bank intervention in the market. It claims that “sterilisation means that domestic interest rates continue to be relatively high, perpetuating inflows.” The assertion is less than sound on both the issues:
A more recent (August 2011) IMF Staff Discussion Note on “The Effectiveness of
Cited in original Report on Currency and Finance, RBI, 2010. Original source: Laeven and Valencia (2008), Reinhart and Rogoff (2008).
flows. This, to say the least, is strange when the 2006 IMF paper cited above clearly finds no “evidence in support of the growth benefits of capital account liberalisation”! The fact is that (i) the global economy lived with capital controls and managed exchange rates for a quarter

may 26, 2012 vol xlviI no 21
EPW